Incentivising the Energy Transition

Current Situation

Currently the energy transition is incentivised by an uncoordinated mish-mash of levies, charges, bans and regulations. Examples include:

  • The European Trading System, topped up by the in some countries by a levy, of the order of €30-40/tonne of carbon emissions;
  • The phase-out of fossil fuelled car sales;
  • Various environmental incentives (such as ROCs [Renewable Obligation Certificates, of which no new ones are being issued] and CfDs [Contracts for Difference]) paid for in levies on energy bills.

By being a variety of incompatible mechanisms, they leave gaps (such as incentivising the large-scale long-duration electricity storage that is necessary for a cost-effective, resilient and reliable energy transition) and perverse incentives (such as peaker plants made of gas-fired reciprocating engines).
The sum total of these measures falls well short of the real societal cost of emissions which ranges up to £575/tonne of CO2 equivalent (tCO2e) (~€673). We should certainly be using values that incorporate the costs imposed on the entire world by our UK emissions; these values are all well in excess of £120/tCO2e (~€140) – in the linked document, this corresponds to central or low figures derived by the three models for 2050. Unless we do that, we’re just exporting suffering onto the rest of the world in order to privilege excessively cavalier attitudes towards climate change among British industry and consumers.
Much better would be to introduce a carbon tax, beloved of economists and greens alike. However that is politically difficult, as the 2019 campaign against fuel taxes in France (the Gilets Jaunes movement) demonstrated, and which is why no country in the world has implemented them yet. The main reasons for this are the design of the tax, perceived losing-out of the poor, and timing. All can be fixed. Especially if fixed soon.

Emissions Added Tax

The fairest way to charge for emissions is via a carbon tax, structured like VAT (an Emissions Added Tax?). This would mean that each person or business only pays for the carbon equivalent that it adds.
It would have to be levied on imports at either a standard rate (per product) or a rate that the exporters can prove, if lower, and either of these deducting any carbon tax (or similar) paid on the other side. Correspondingly, exports would need to be re-credited in the same way to keep the playing-field level, thereby enabling British companies to continue to compete on a world stage. Such levies on imports / refunds on exports would have to be transparent and challengeable by both British and foreign parties, in order not to engender trade disputes. Therefore they will be broad-brush to begin with, fine-tuning as they go along and allowing particularly good and bad performing companies to be given the special consideration that they merit. This in turn extends the decarbonisation incentive beyond our shores.
While this would apply to the vast majority of products, and possibly extendable to some services too, there would be special cases that would require special treatment, such as international shipping and aviation, for which various methods could be proposed.

Uses of Funds from the Emissions Added Tax

The uses to which an Emissions Added Taxis put are crucial to its political and social acceptance, and its effects on the economy. This yields a few priority areas:

  • Those who lose out from the tax and would find it difficult to pay – those on low income who can’t afford to make the changes;
  • Subsidies for carbon-beneficial modifications to buildings, such as insulation and heat pumps (which in turn reduce subsidy needs of those who lose out);
  • Public transport, especially on routes with lower demand / services;
  • Full-scale commercial demonstrator projects of diverse clean technologies in all sectors (heating, transportation, electricity, industry etc.); and
  • Pay down the national debt.

It is very important that the first three types of payment (to those who lose out, and for public transport) must not be related to their fuel consumption, or these payments / subsidies would disincentivise (or reduce the incentives towards) reducing their carbon consumption and/or emissions.

Press enquiries

For any press enquiries, please contact:

Press@storelectric.com

READ MORE

Storelectric, an energy storage company dedicated to advancing industry’s journey towards net zero, has announced its expansion into Teesside, highlighting the region’s …

On March 13th 2024 the House of Lords Science and Technology Committee published a report detailing the UK’s urgent need for long-duration …

Storelectric’s growing relationship with Uzbekistan Storelectric’s prospects in Uzbekistan are continuing to develop. Uzbekistan has shown considerable interest in Storelectric’s capacity to …